Egypt's Population Program: Assessing 25 Years of Family Planning
Publication date: 2006
Egypt’s Population Program: Assessing 25 Years of Family Planning Scott Moreland March 2006 Egypt’s Population Program: Assessing 25 Years of Family Planning March 2006 This brief was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development. The author’s views expressed in this publication do not necessarily reflect the view of USAID or the United States Government. Contents Acknowledgments . iv Executive Summary (English and Arabic) . v Introduction. 1 Egypt’s Demographic Transition and Family Planning. 1 What Would Egypt Be Like if the Demographic Transition Had Not Occurred? . 5 What Are the Health Benefits of Lower Fertility?. 10 What Are the Benefits in Terms of Lower Expenditures on Health and Social Programs?. 15 How Do the Savings Compare with the Costs of Family Planning?. 20 Conclusion . 21 iii Acknowledgments Over the last 15 years, I have benefited from studying and responding to issues facing Egypt’s education and health sectors; during nearly eight of those years, I lived and worked in Egypt. I was privileged to collaborate with many of the pioneers of Egypt’s family planning program and to attend the 1994 International Conference on Population and Development in Cairo, contributing in a small way to that event by assisting the National Population Council with its preparations for the watershed conference. This study therefore represents the culmination of a period in my professional life spent working in Egypt. The study has benefited from the comments and assistance of several colleagues that I would like to acknowledge. They include Dr. Hussein Abdel-Aziz Sayed, Country Director of the POLICY Project, Egypt, and all of the capable staff of the POLICY/Egypt office whose persistent search for data made the study possible. Similarly, I am indebted to Rachel Sanders of the Futures Group for her research assistance. John Ross generously provided data and guidance on the analysis of family planning and child survival. Warren Robinson, who knows well the Egyptian family planning experience and whose own work complements this study, provided valuable insights as well as gracious access to his data set. The paper also benefited from careful reading by Suneeta Sharma, Carol Shepherd, and Bill Winfrey of the Futures Group. Finally, I would like to thank the POLICY Project and USAID for their support for this study and their patience in allowing me the time to complete it. iv Executive Summary This report reviews the progress made to date under Egypt’s family planning (FP) program and estimates the benefits that have already been realized. It documents the effects of the FP program on Egypt’s demographic transition through a review of the country’s major demographic indicators. To estimate the benefits realized, a scenario of a less successful FP program was created and compared with the cumulative public sector savings achieved as a result of Egypt’s actual FP program for the period of 1980–2005. The health benefits for children and mothers were also analyzed. Overall, Egypt’s demography in the last century has followed a classic transition from high fertility and mortality to lower fertility and mortality. The total fertility rate fell from 5.6 in 1976 to 3.1 in 2005; it is clear that increases in FP use have been a significant factor in this decline. During that same time period, the contraceptive prevalence rate increased from 18.9 percent to 59 percent, and data show this trend was largely accomplished by an increased number of service delivery outlets. For example, the number of FP clinics in the public and NGO sectors rose from 3,862 in 1981 to 6,005 in mid-2005—an increase of more than 50 percent. Resources allocated to family planning have also been on the rise, increasing by approximately 400 percent from 1989 to 2003. In 2004, Egypt’s crude birth rate (CBR) was 25.6, with a crude death rate (CDR) of 6.4. The benefits of the FP program to date have been substantial, resulting in • a population that is smaller by 12 million (nearly the size of Cairo); • a more favorable age distribution, with 10 million fewer young people (not old enough to work); • a lower infant mortality rate, resulting in more than 3 million fewer infant deaths during the last 25 years; • a lower under-5 child mortality rate, resulting in about 6 million fewer early-childhood deaths during the last 25 years; and • fewer maternal deaths, with 17,000 mothers’ lives saved over the last 25 years. The savings gained through the above results and a highly cost-effective FP program have led to additional broader benefits. The LE 2,402 million spent on family planning between 1980 and 2005 was more than offset by the LE 45,838 million estimated cost savings in child health, education, and food subsidies. These cost savings have allowed Egypt to maintain and improve the quality of public services in these sectors and ultimately the quality of life of Egyptians. Undoubtedly, as other studies have shown, other sectors, such as general health, housing, employment, and the economy, have also benefited from the FP program. With an expected decline in donor funding for family planning in the near future, it is clear that Egypt would be wise to maintain the program at current and even higher levels by allocating funds to replace those expected to be reduced by international donors. v وﺗﺰﻳﺪ هﺬﻩ اﻟﻮﻓﻮرات ﺑﺪرﺟﺔ آﺒﻴﺮة ﻋﻦ اﻟﺘﻜﻠﻔﺔ اﻹﺟﻤﺎﻟﻴﺔ . اﻹﻧﻔﺎق ﻋﻠﻰ ﺻﺤﺔ اﻷﻃﻔﺎل واﻟﺘﻌﻠﻴﻢ ودﻋﻢ اﻟﻐﺬاء أﻟﻒ 4,2اﻟﻤﻘﺪرة ﻟﻠﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة، ﺧﻼل ﻧﻔﺲ اﻟﻔﺘﺮة ﻣﺤﻞ اﻟﺪراﺳﺔ، واﻟﺘﻲ ﺗﺼﻞ إﻟﻰ ﺣﻮاﻟﻲ . ﻣﻠﻴﻮن ﺟﻨﻴﺔ ﻔﺮﺻﺔ ﻟﻠﺤﻜﻮﻣﺔ اﻟﻤﺼﺮﻳﺔ ﻟﻠﻌﻤﻞ ﻋﻠﻰ اﺳﺘﻤﺮارﻳﺔ وﺑﺪون ﺷﻚ، ﻓﻘﺪ أﺗﺎﺣﺖ ﺗﻠﻚ اﻟﻮﻓﻮرات ﻓﻲ اﻷﻧﻔﺎق، اﻟ واﻻرﺗﻘﺎء ﺑﻤﺴﺘﻮى اﻟﺨﺪﻣﺎت اﻟﻌﺎﻣﺔ ﻓﻲ اﻟﻘﻄﺎﻋﺎت إﻟﻰ ﺗﻌﺮﺿﻨﺎ ﻟﻬﺎ، آﻤﺎ أﻧﻬﺎ ﺗﺼﺐ ﻓﻲ اﻟﻨﻬﺎﻳﺔ ﻓﻲ إﻃﺎر اﻟﺠﻬﻮد وﺑﺎﻹﺿﺎﻓﺔ إﻟﻰ ذﻟﻚ، أوﺿﺤﺖ اﻟﻌﺪﻳﺪ ﻣﻦ اﻟﺪراﺳﺎت أن اﻟﻘﻄﺎﻋﺎت . اﻟﺴﺎﻋﻴﺔ ﻟﻼرﺗﻘﺎء ﺑﻨﻮﻋﻴﺔ اﻟﺤﻴﺎة ﻟﻠﻤﺼﺮﻳﻴﻦ ﻌﺎﻣﺔ واﻹﺳﻜﺎن واﻟﻌﻤﺎﻟﺔ واﻻﻗﺘﺼﺎد ﺑﺼﻔﺔ ﻋﺎﻣﺔ، ﺗﺴﺘﻔﻴﺪ أﻳﻀﺎ ﻣﻦ اﻹﻧﺠﺎزات اﻟﺘﻲ اﻷﺧﺮى ﻣﺜﻞ اﻟﺼﺤﺔ اﻟ . ﻳﺤﻘﻘﻬﺎ اﻟﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة وﺑﺎﻟﻨﻈﺮاﻟﻰ اﻻﻧﺨﻔﺎض اﻟﻤﺘﻮﻗﻊ ﻓﻲ اﻟﻤﺴﺎﻋﺪات اﻟﻤﺨﺼﺼﺔ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ﻓﻲ اﻟﻤﺪى اﻟﻘﺮﻳﺐ، ﻓﺎﻧﻪ ﻳﺘﻮﺟﺐ ﻋﻠﻰ ﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ، ﺑﻞ واﻟﻌﻤﻞ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺗﻮﺳﻴﻊ ﻣﺼﺮ اﻟﻤﺤﺎﻓﻈﺔ ﻋﻠﻰ إﺳﺘﻤﺮاﻳﺔ اﻟﻤﺴﺘﻮى اﻟﺤﺎﻟﻲ ﻟﻠﺒﺮﻧﺎ ﻧﻄﺎﻗﻪ، ﻣﻦ ﺧﻼل ﺗﻮﻓﻴﺮ اﻟﻤﻮارد اﻟﻤﺎﻟﻴﺔ اﻟﻤﻄﻠﻮﺑﺔ ﻻﺳﺘﻌﺎﺿﺔ اﻟﻌﺠﺰ اﻟﻤﺘﻮﻗﻊ ﻧﺘﻴﺠﺔ ﻻﻧﺨﻔﺎض اﻟﻤﻌﻮﻧﺎت . اﻟﺨﺎرﺟﻴﺔ iv ﻣﻠﺨﺺ ﺗﻨﻔﻴﺬي ن ﺳﻨﺔ ﻃﻮال ﻓﺘﺮة اﻟﺨﻤﺴﺔ وﻋﺸﺮو اﻟﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮةﻳﺴﺘﻌﺮض هﺬا اﻟﺘﻘﺮﻳﺮ اﻟﻨﺘﺎﺋﺞ اﻟﺘﻲ ﺣﻘﻘﻬﺎ ، وذﻟﻚ ﻣﻦ ﺧﻼل اﻟﺴﻌﻲ ﻟﺘﻘﺪﻳﺮ اﻟﻌﺎﺋﺪات اﻟﺘﻲ ﺗﻢ اﻟﻮﺻﻮل إﻟﻴﻬﺎ، واﻟﻌﻤﻞ ﻋﻠﻰ (5002 – 0891)اﻟﻤﺎﺿﻴﺔ ﺗﻮﺛﻴﻖ اﻧﻌﻜﺎﺳﺎت ﺑﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ ﺗﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ﻋﻠﻰ اﻟﺘﺤﻮل اﻟﺪﻳﻤﻮﺟﺮاﻓﻰ ﻟﻤﺼﺮ ﻋﻦ ﻃﺮﻳﻖ ﻣﺮاﺟﻌﺔ اﻟﻤﺆﺷﺮات ﻳﻘﻮم ﻋﻠﻰ اﻓﺘﺮاض " ﺳﻴﻨﺎرﻳﻮ"وﻗﺪ ﺗﻄﻠﺐ ﺗﻘﺪﻳﺮ هﺬﻩ اﻟﻌﺎﺋﺪات اﻟﻤﺤﻘﻘﺔ، ﺗﺒﻨﻰ . اﻟﺪﻳﻤﻮﺟﺮاﻓﻴﺔ اﻷﺳﺎﺳﻴﺔ ﻟﻠﺪوﻟﺔ ﻣﺴﺘﻮﻳﺎت أﻗﻞ ﻟﻨﺠﺎﺣﺎت ﺑﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ ﺗﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة وﺑﺎﻟﺘﺎﻟﻲ ﻣﻘﺎرﻧﺔ اﻟﺘﻜﻠﻔﺔ اﻹﺿﺎﻓﻴﺔ اﻟﻤﻄﻠﻮﺑﺔ ﻷﻋﺪاد اﻟﺴﻜﺎن اﻟﻤﻘﺪرة ﻓﻲ هﺬﻩ اﻟﺤﺎﻟﺔ، ﻣﻊ اﻟﻮﻓﻮرات اﻟﺘﺮاآﻤﻴﺔ ﻟﻺﻧﻔﺎق اﻟﺤﻜﻮﻣﻲ اﻟﺘﻲ أﻣﻜﻦ ﺗﺤﻘﻴﻘﻬﺎ ﻧﺘﻴﺠﺔ ﻹﻧﺠﺎزات اﻟﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻔﻌﻠﻲ . ل اﻟﻔﺘﺮة اﻟﺰﻣﻨﻴﺔ اﻟﺘﻲ ﺗﻐﻄﻴﻬﺎ اﻟﺪراﺳﺔﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ﻓﻲ ﻣﺼﺮ، ﺧﻼ ﺗﺸﻴﺮ ﺑﻮﺿﻮح إﻟﻰ أﻧﻪ ﻳﻌﻜﺲ ﻲوﺑﺼﻔﺔ ﻋﺎﻣﺔ، ﻓﺎن دراﺳﺔ اﻟﺘﻄﻮر اﻟﺪﻳﻤﻮﺟﺮاﻓﻰ ﻟﻤﺼﺮ ﺧﻼل اﻟﻘﺮن اﻟﻤﺎﺿ اﻟﻨﻤﻂ اﻟﺘﻘﻠﻴﺪي ﻟﻠﺘﺤﻮل ﻧﺤﻮ اﻟﻤﺴﺘﻮﻳﺎت اﻟﻤﻨﺨﻔﻀﺔ ﻟﻺﻧﺠﺎب واﻟﻮﻓﻴﺎت ﺑﺪﻻ ﻣﻦ اﻟﻘﻴﻢ اﻟﻤﺮﺗﻔﻌﺔ اﻟﻤﺸﺎهﺪة ﻓﻲ ﻃﻔﻞ ﻓﻲ 6,5ﻣﻦ ( ﻣﺘﻮﺳﻂ ﻋﺪد اﻷﻃﻔﺎل ﻟﻜﻞ ﺳﻴﺪة) ﻧﺨﻔﺾ ﻣﻌﺪل اﻹﻧﺠﺎب اﻟﻜﻠﻰ وﻓﻰ اﻟﻔﺘﺮة اﻷﺧﻴﺮة، ا. اﻟﺒﺪاﻳﺔ ، وهﻮ ﻣﺎ ﻳﺮﺟﻊ ﺑﺼﻮرة أﺳﺎﺳﻴﺔ إﻟﻰ اﻟﺰﻳﺎدة اﻟﻜﺒﻴﺮة ﻓﻲ ﻧﺴﺒﺔ 5002 ﻃﻔﻞ ﻓﻲ ﻋﺎم1,3 إﻟﻰ 6791ﻋﺎم وﺗﻮﺿﺢ اﻟﺒﻴﺎﻧﺎت أﻧﻪ ﺧﻼل ﻧﻔﺲ اﻟﻔﺘﺮة اﻟﺰﻣﻨﻴﺔ، ارﺗﻔﻌﺖ ﻧﺴﺒﺔ ﻣﻤﺎرﺳﺔ ﺗﻨﻈﻴﻢ . ﻣﺴﺘﺨﺪﻣﻲ وﺳﺎﺋﻞ ﺗﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ، وذﻟﻚ ﻧﺘﻴﺠﺔ 5002ﻓﻲ ﻋﺎم % 0,95إﻟﻰ % 9,81ﺮة، ﺑﻴﻦ اﻟﻨﺴﺎء اﻟﻤﺘﺰوﺟﺎت ﻓﻲ ﺳﻦ اﻹﻧﺠﺎب، ﻣﻦ اﻷﺳ وﻋﻠﻰ ﺳﺒﻴﻞ اﻟﻤﺜﺎل، ﻓﻘﺪ زادت أﻋﺪاد وﺣﺪات ﺗﻘﺪﻳﻢ . ﻣﺒﺎﺷﺮة ﻟﻠﺰﻳﺎدة اﻟﻮاﺿﺤﺔ ﻓﻲ أﻋﺪاد وﺣﺪات ﺗﻘﺪﻳﻢ اﻟﺨﺪﻣﺔ ﻓﻲ 5006إﻟﻰ 1891 ﻓﻲ ﻋﺎم 2683ﺧﺪﻣﺎت ﺗﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة، ﻓﻲ اﻟﻘﻄﺎﻋﻴﻦ اﻟﺤﻜﻮﻣﻲ وﻏﻴﺮ اﻟﺤﻜﻮﻣﻲ، ﻣﻦ وﻓﻰ ﻧﻔﺲ اﻟﻮﻗﺖ، ارﺗﻔﻌﺖ اﻟﻤﺨﺼﺼﺎت اﻟﻤﺎﻟﻴﺔ %. 05، وهﻮ ﻣﺎ ﻳﺸﻴﺮ إﻟﻰ زﻳﺎدة ﺗﺘﻌﺪى 5002ﻣﻨﺘﺼﻒ ﻋﺎم وﻳﻘﺪر ﻣﻌﺪل اﻟﻤﻮاﻟﻴﺪ اﻻﺟﻤﺎﻟﻰ ﻟﻤﺼﺮ، . 3002 إﻟﻰ 9891، ﺧﻼل اﻟﻔﺘﺮة ﻣﻦ %004ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻰ 4,6ل اﻟﻮﻓﻴﺎت اﻻﺟﻤﺎﻟﻰ إﻟﻰ ﺣﻮاﻟﻲ ﻟﻜﻞ أﻟﻒ ﻣﻦ اﻟﺴﻜﺎن ﺑﻴﻨﻤﺎ ﺗﺼﻞ ﻗﻴﻤﺔ ﻣﻌﺪ6,52، ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻰ 4002ﻓﻲ ﻋﺎم . ﻟﻜﻞ أﻟﻒ ﻣﻦ اﻟﺴﻜﺎن وﺗﻌﻜﺲ اﻟﻨﺘﺎﺋﺞ اﻟﺘﺎﻟﻴﺔ اﻟﺘﻲ رﺻﺪﺗﻬﺎ اﻟﺪراﺳﺔ، أهﻤﻴﺔ وﺿﺨﺎﻣﺔ اﻟﻌﺎﺋﺪات اﻟﺘﻲ ﺣﻘﻘﻬﺎ اﻟﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ : ، واﻟﺘﻲ ﻳﻤﻜﻦ إﻳﺠﺎزهﺎ ﻓﻴﻤﺎ ﻳﻠﻲ5002-0891اﻷﺳﺮة ﺧﻼل اﻟﻔﺘﺮة ﺗﺴﺎوى ﺗﻘﺮﻳﺒﺎ ﻋﺪد ) ﻣﻠﻴﻮن ﻧﺴﻤﺔ 21، ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻲ ﺗﻨﺎﻗﺺ اﻟﺰﻳﺎدة ﻓﻲ أﻋﺪد اﻟﺴﻜﺎن، ﺧﻼل اﻟﻔﺘﺮة • ،( ﺳﻜﺎن اﻟﻘﺎهﺮة ﺗﻮزﻳﻊ ﻋﻤﺮي ﻟﻠﺴﻜﺎن أآﺜﺮ ﻣﻼﺋﻤﺔ، ﺣﻴﺚ ﺗﻘﻞ أﻋﺪادهﻢ ﻓﻲ اﻟﻔﺌﺎت اﻟﻌﻤﺮﻳﺔ اﻟﺼﻐﻴﺮة، أﻗﻞ ﻣﻦ • ،(وﻟﻜﻨﻬﻢ ﻣﺎزاﻟﻮا ﺧﺎرج ﻗﻮة اﻟﻌﻤﻞ) ﻣﻠﻴﻮن ﻧﺴﻤﺔ 01 ﺳﻨﺔ، ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻲ 51 ﻴﺎت ﻓﻲ اﻟﺴﻨﺔ اﻷوﻟﻰ ﻣﻦ ﻣﻌﺪﻻت أﻗﻞ ﻟﻮﻓﻴﺎت اﻟﺮﺿﻊ، ﻣﻤﺎ أﺳﻔﺮ ﻋﻦ اﻧﺨﻔﺎض أﻋﺪاد اﻟﻮﻓ • ﻣﻠﻴﻮن ﻧﺴﻤﺔ ﺧﻼل اﻟﺨﻤﺴﺔ وﻋﺸﺮون ﺳﻨﺔ اﻟﻤﺎﺿﻴﺔ،3اﻟﻌﻤﺮ، ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻲ ﻣﻠﻴﻮن 6ﻣﻌﺪﻻت أﻗﻞ ﻟﻮﻓﻴﺎت اﻷﻃﻔﺎل أﻗﻞ ﻣﻦ ﺧﻤﺲ ﺳﻨﻮات، ﻣﻤﺎ ﺳﺎهﻢ ﻓﻲ إﻧﻘﺎذ ﺣﻴﺎة ﺣﻮاﻟﻲ • ﻃﻔﻞ ﺧﻼل اﻟﻔﺘﺮة ﻣﺤﻞ اﻟﺪراﺳﺔ، . ﻋﻠﻰ ﺣﻴﺎﺗﻬﻢ أﻣﻜﻦ اﻟﺤﻔﺎظ000,71اﻧﺨﻔﺎض وﻓﻴﺎت اﻷﻣﻬﺎت، ﺧﻼل هﺬﻩ اﻟﻔﺘﺮة، ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻲ • وﻗﺪ ﺳﺎهﻤﺖ اﻟﻮﻓﻮرات اﻟﺘﻲ ﺣﻘﻘﺘﻬﺎ اﻟﻨﺘﺎﺋﺞ اﻟﺴﺎﺑﻖ اﻹﺷﺎرة إﻟﻴﻬﺎ، وآﺬا اﻟﺘﻄﺒﻴﻖ اﻟﻔﻌﺎل ﻻﻋﺘﺒﺎرات اﻟﺮﺷﺎدة اﻻﻗﺘﺼﺎدﻳﺔ ﺧﻼل ﺗﻨﻔﻴﺬ اﻟﺒﺮﻧﺎﻣﺞ اﻟﻘﻮﻣﻲ ﻟﺘﻨﻈﻴﻢ اﻷﺳﺮة ، ﻓﻲ اﻟﻮﺻﻮل إﻟﻰ اﻟﻤﺰﻳﺪ ﻣﻦ اﻟﻤﻨﺎﻓﻊ اﻹﺿﺎﻓﻴﺔ أﻟﻒ ﻣﻠﻴﻮن ﺟﻨﻴﺔ، ﻧﺘﻴﺠﺔ ﻻﻧﺨﻔﺎض ﻣﺘﻄﻠﺒﺎت8,54واﻟﻮﻓﻮرات ﻓﻲ اﻟﻨﻔﻘﺎت اﻟﻌﺎﻣﺔ، اﻟﺘﻲ ﻗﺪرت ﺑﺤﻮاﻟﻲ Introduction Egypt’s family program has achi with the prospect of donor phase to document the program’s achie Egypt. To that end, this report reviews estimates the benefits that the nat with other countries and, by relyi and crude birth rate (CBR), de demographic transition and exam already realized, the report const planning program and compares the one used by the RAPID a retrospectively—for the period 1 result of the successful family p and mothers. It clearly shows tha in Egypt. Egypt’s Demographic Tr In the last century, the overall pa high fertility and high mortality transition. Figure 1 shows the pat the crude death rate (CDR) 34, w death rate started to fall precip remained high. By 1960, the pop the 1960s that fertility started to d Demographic Tr 19 40 19 50 19 60 19 65 19 70 19 75 19 80 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 19 00 19 10 19 20 19 30 1 eved considerable progress and now enjoys political support. However, out for the family planning program (especially by USAID), it is useful vements to date and to estimate the benefits that have already accrued to the progress achieved to date by Egypt’s family planning program and ion has realized since the early 1980s. The report provides a comparison ng on major demographic indicators such as the total fertility rate (TFR) monstrates the impacts of the family planning program on Egypt’s ines Egypt’s total population and age structure. To estimate the benefits ructs a “counterfactual” scenario that supposes a less successful family its outcome with the actual trajectory of events. Using a model similar to nd POLICY projects for prospective analysis, the report estimates 980 through 2005—the cumulative public sector savings realized as a lanning program. The model also estimates health benefits for children t the family planning program is responsible for the gains realized to date ansition and Family Planning ttern of Egypt’s demographic history followed a classic transition from to lower fertility and lower mortality, thus resulting in a demographic h of the birth and death rates since 1900. In 1900, the CBR was 45.7 and ith an annual population growth rate of 1.3 percent. In the 1920s, the itously and, with it, the population growth rate increased as fertility ulation growth rate had climbed to 2.7 percent per year. It was not until ecline. The current CBR is 25.6, with a CDR of 6.4. Figure 1. ansition in Egypt 1900-2004 19 85 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 CBR CDR Source: Robinson and Zanaty (2005); CAPMAS. Many factors can account for a decline in fertility, including: • An increase in the age at marriage and/or a decline in the percentage of women of reproductive age who are married; • An increase in natural sterility; • An increase in the period of postpartum infertility associated with prolonged breastfeeding; • An increase in spontaneous and induced abortion; and • Increased use of contraception. Such factors are measured by index numbers that demographers call proximate determinates. Table 1 demonstrates that, among these determinates, changes in the use of contraception is the single most important factor responsible for fertility decline, falling from 0.75 to 0.43, whereas the marriage index has not declined nearly as dramatically (from 0.65 to 0.57.) Postpartum infecundabilty remained fairly stable over the last 20 years. Table 1. Evolution of Proximate Determinates Index 1980 1988 1992 1995 2000 Index of contraception 0.75 0.60 0.51 0.50 0.43 Index of marriage 0.65 0.60 0.58 0.60 0.57 Index of infecundability 0.74 0.72 0.75 0.74 0.77 Source: Robinson and Zanaty (1995, 2005). Table 2 clearly shows that increases in family planning use over time have been accompanied by a decline in fertility. The contraceptive prevalence rate (CPR) increased from 18.9 percent in 1976 to 59 percent in 2005. During the same period, the TFR fell from 5.6 to 3.1, according to the latest Demographic and Health Survey (DHS). Table 2. Trends in TFR and CPR Year TFR CPR 1976 5.6 18.8 1980 5.3 24.2 1984 4.9 30.3 1986 4.4 37.8 1992 4.1 47.1 1995 3.9 47.8 1997 3.6 54.6 1998 3.3 56.0 2000 3.5 56.1 2003 3.2 60.1 2005 3.1 59.0 Source: Various DHS reports; 1976 CPR: author’s estimate. Family Planning Service Availability Ample data show that the increase in contraceptive prevalence has resulted from an increase in the number of service delivery outlets. Figure 2 indicates that the number of family planning 2 clinics in the public and NGO (nongovernmental organization) sectors rose from 3,862 in 1981 to 6,005 in mid-2005, a capacity increase of over 50 percent. Figure 2. Growth in Family Planning Clinics 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 6,000 7,000 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Government NGO Source: NPC. Annual Analytical Statistical Family Planning Services Reports, 1981 to 2004. Similarly, Table 3 shows that the growth in clinical capacity was accompanied by an increase in the number of pharmacies in Egypt; pharmacies supply pills, condoms, other barrier methods, and sometimes injectables. Pharmacy growth rose by over 700 percent, from 3,880 outlets in 1978 (almost the same number of family planning clinics) to over 27,000 outlets in 2004. Table 3. Growth in Pharmacies Year Number of Pharmacies 1978 3,880 1979 4,500 1984 7,042 1987 8,962 1990 12,070 1992 13,761 1993 15,777 1994 14,711 1995 16,249 1997 16,503 1998 20,838 1999 19,544 2001 27,160 2003 29,304 2004 27,179 Source: CAPMAS: Statistical Yearbooks, 1979 to 2004. 3 Couple-Years of Protection The expansion in clinical and pharmacy capacity was accompanied by an increase in the number of contraceptives distributed as measured by couple-years of protection (CYPs), an indicator that measures the approximate number of couples who are protected for one year by the use of all methods of contraception. The indicator aggregates the quantities of all contraceptives used by couples by applying appropriate weighting factors to each type of contraceptive. Figure 3 shows that CYPs increased from 1.1 million in 1981 to 6.5 million in 2004, for an increase of more than 600 percent. The fluctuation in CYPs in the early 1990s is most likely explained by the transition that took place from the highly aggressive social marketing campaign launched in the mid-1980s (Family of the Future) to the campaign supported under the USAID bilateral program. What is important, however, is the overall increase. Figure 3. Growth in Family Planning (Couple-Years of Protection) 0 1,000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 4,000,000 5,000,000 6,000,000 7,000,000 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 C YP Source: NPC. Annual Analytical Statistical Family Planning Services Reports, 1981 to 2004. Family Planning Expenditures Resources allocated to family planning have also been on the rise, increasing by 400 percent in nominal terms from 1989 to 2003. In 1988 to 1989, total spending by the public, private, and NGO sectors was estimated at LE 44.7 million. By 2002–2003, the figure had increased to LE 206.2 million. Users of Family Planning The above phenomena have been accompanied by an increase in the number of women who use contraceptives. The increase in the CPR in combination with the natural growth in the number of married women of reproductive age has led to spectacular growth in the number of women who regularly use contraceptives. In 1980, 1.5 million women used some form of family planning. Current estimates of the number of married women, combined with the latest DHS suggesting that 6.4 million women use contraceptives, point to an increase of 400 percent as of 2005. 4 Table 4. Total Expenditures on Family Planning by Type of Agency Fiscal Year NGOs Government of Egypt Donor Agencies Client Payments Total 1988–1989 243,045 20,873,347 19,914,857 3,679,611 44,710,860 1989–1990 456,475 22,296,679 31,198,496 6,448,728 60,400,378 1990–1991 1,499,080 24,463,323 39,282,950 7,059,875 72,305,228 1991–1992 1,368,559 29,566,150 39,218,511 9,216,419 79,369,639 1992–1993 2,044,418 24,848,395 35,393,209 9,947,464 72,233,484 1993–1994 1,707,683 29,409,294 26,942,872 8,505,452 66,565,301 1994–1995 1,229,779 52,666,486 34,390,242 7,324,477 95,610,984 1995–1996 1,117,568 45,445,310 41,734,131 9,546,471 97,843,480 1996–1997 1,130,566 57,993,888 52,323,778 8,596,190 120,044,422 1997–1998 927,334 83,403,992 61,511,406 10,242,190 156,084,922 1998–1999 812,504 90,892,285 53,935,055 9,092,186 154,732,030 1999–2000 125,807 94,823,727 58,831,694 10,723,721 164,504,949 2000–2001 109,044 119,059,356 75,067,763 13,828,839 208,065,002 2001–2002 2,987 125,551,109 82,446,658 15,070,578 223,071,332 2002–2003 52,842 121,756,736 67,873,356 16,562,497 206,245,430 Source: POLICY II Project/Egypt (forthcoming), The Trends of the Cost of Family Planning Program in Egypt. Figure 4. Family Planning Users 0 1,000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 4,000,000 5,000,000 6,000,000 7,000,000 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Source: Spectrum projections by author. What Would Egypt Be Like if the Demographic Transition Had Not Occurred? To determine what Egypt would be like if the demographic transition had not occurred, we must estimate the trajectory that fertility and mortality would have taken in the case of a less successful family planning 5 program absent a demographic transition or a slower-paced transition. We must therefore construct a hypothetical counterfactual scenario and compare it with the actual course of demographic events. Of course, we cannot be certain what would have happened in the absence of program interventions, but our counterfactual scenario attem urred in such a case. To this end, we make some assumptio successful as Egypt in achiev contraception. First, we assume that overall m trajectory under both the counte construct a counterfactual fertil period started to take shape in period 1980 to 2005. As we are affects fertility, we will constru view of known events, we need One method of determining th evidenced in 1980. However, li 1980, and existing data are in Instead, to develop an idea of C terms of contraceptive change annual change by region for cou We see that Egypt’s average an region (1.39 versus 1.15). By co for all women and 0.72 for marr in CPR. 0.53 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Sub-Sa Afr E 1 For example, Robinson and Zanat between 1975 and 1980. pts to show what probably would have occ ns that reflect what has occurred in countries that have not been as ing a demographic transition and realizing the widespread use of ortality, as measured by the crude death rate, would follow the same rfactual scenario and what we call the actual scenario. Second, we need to ity trajectory over the period of interest. Given that the family planning the late 1970s and early 1980s, we construct scenarios for the 25-year interested in family planning and have demonstrated that family planning ct our two scenarios in terms of change in contraceptive prevalence. In to find a trajectory for CPR for our counterfactual scenario. e counterfactual trajectory simply projects the trend in CPR growth ttle reliable data on contraceptive use are available for the period before consistent, making it impossible to establish a trend in CPR growth.1 PR growth in Egypt, we looked at the experience of other countries in over the course of the last 15 or so years. Figure 5 shows the average ntries that had undertaken two or more Demographic and Health Surveys. nual change in CPR for married women exceeded the average for the ntrast, sub-Saharan Africa exhibited very slow growth, with a rate of 0.53 ied women. The Asian Tiger countries recorded the highest annual gains Figure 5. Average Annual Change in CPR (Any Method) 1.38 1.97 1.59 0.72 1.15 2.15 1.83 haran ica North Africa/West Asia/Europe South & Southeast Asia Latin America & Caribbean All Women Married gypt 1.39 Source: Various DHS data downloaded from DHS website. y (2005) report a simultaneous fall in fertility and contraceptive prevalence 6 In constructing the counterfactual and imagining what might have happened in Egypt in the case of a weak family planning program, we determined that it is probably not reasonable to assume that no growth in CPR occurred. We therefore took the experience of sub-Saharan Africa as a worst-case scenario for our weak program model and selected an annual increase of 0.5 percent for the CPR in the counterfactual scenario. Figure 6 presents application of the counterfactual as compared with actual growth. As we saw earlier, Egypt’s 1976 CPR was 18.9 percent. By 2005, according to the latest DHS, the CPR had reached 59 percent (indicated by the solid line in Figure 6), representing the scenario we term the actual scenario. By contrast, if Egypt followed a path more similar to that of sub-Saharan Africa with a CPR annual change of only 0.5 percent, Egypt’s 2005 CPR would have increased to only 33.5 during the 25-year retrospective projection. Thus, the dashed line in Figure 6 shows the counterfactual CPR scenario. Figure 6. Contraceptive Prevalence Rate Under Two Scenarios 0.00 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 70.00 19 76 19 77 19 78 19 79 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual Source: Actual scenario: various DHS for Egypt; Counterfactual: author’s calculations. Fertility Impact We used the FamPlan/Spectrum Model to estimate the impact on fertility of the slower change in contraceptive use. If the counterfactual scenario had in fact unfolded, the fertility rate would have declined from 5.6 in 1976 to 4.65 in 2005. However, in reality, the latest DHS for 2005 estimated a current fertility rate of 3.1, a difference of 1.5 children per woman, as shown in Figure 7. 7 Figure demog have b such th have b percen nearly Figure 7. Fertility Under Two Scenarios 0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 19 76 19 77 19 78 19 79 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 TF R Counterfactual Actual Source: Actual scenario: various DHS for Egypt; Counterfactual: author’s calculations. 8 shows the impact of the counterfactual assumptions about contraceptive growth on the raphic transition. With a higher counterfactual fertility rate, the number of births would obviously een greater; therefore, the crude birth rate would have fallen much less dramatically than in reality at progress toward the demographic transition would have been slower. By 2004, the CBR would een 34 versus 25. In terms of the population growth rate, the actual annual rate is estimated at 1.9 t in 2004, whereas the counterfactual scenario places the growth rate at 2.8 percent, a difference of 1 percent. Figure 8. Demographic Transition in Egypt 1900-2004 Under Two Scenarios 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 19 00 19 20 19 40 19 60 19 70 19 80 19 90 19 92 19 94 19 96 19 98 20 00 20 02 20 04 CBR CBR Counterfactual CDR Figure 9. Source: Actual numbers: Robinson and Zanaty (2005); Counterfactual: author’s calculations using FamPlan/Spectrum Model. 8 Total Population 1976-2005 0 10,000,000 20,000,000 30,000,000 40,000,000 50,000,000 60,000,000 70,000,000 80,000,000 90,000,000 19 76 19 77 19 78 19 79 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual 83.6 71.6 Source: Author’s calculations based on Spectrum. Figure 9 compares the counterfactual and actual scenarios in terms of total population size. A difference of 1 percent in the growth rate may seem small, yet the compound nature of population growth, especially in the context of an already large population, means that even a low growth rate results in enormous gains in population over time. With a higher rate of growth under the counterfactual’s less successful family planning scenario, Egypt’s population would have been higher today than it is in actuality. By 2005, we estimate that the population would have stood at 83.6 million in contrast to the 71.6 million that we calculate in accordance with our projection under the actual fertility scenario. The difference is 12 million people. High fertility also affects the age structure of the population. Given that fertility by definition affects births, a higher fertility rate translates into a larger number of people in the youngest age groups. Table 5 shows clearly that, under the counterfactual scenario, the population under age 15 years would be significantly greater in terms of numbers and percentages than under the actual scenario. In fact, had fertility not fallen, the counterfactual projection points to 34 million youth under the age of 15 in 2005 versus only 23.8 million under the actual scenario. We saw above that the overall difference in total population between the two scenarios was 12 million. Of that 12 million, 10.1 million—or 84 percent—fell in the age group under age 15. Stated another way, the actual scenario means that Egypt is responsible for meeting the education, health/social service, and employment needs of 10.1 million fewer youth as compared with the service demands imposed by the number of youth projected in the counterfactual. 9 Table 5. Age Structure of the Population Under Two Scenarios Age Counterfactual Actual Number Percent Number Percent 0–4 13,004,100 15.6% 8,357,210 11.7% 5–9 11,100,600 13.3% 8,031,330 11.3% 10–14 9,978,020 11.9% 7,509,750 10.5% 15–19 8,860,280 10.6% 7,503,860 10.5% 20–24 7,541,710 9.0% 6,969,950 9.8% 25–29 6,177,280 7.4% 6,065,330 8.5% 30–34 4,686,060 5.6% 4,686,060 6.6% 35–39 4,470,440 5.3% 4,470,440 6.3% 40–44 4,484,610 5.4% 4,484,610 6.3% 45–49 3,452,020 4.1% 3,452,020 4.8% 50–54 2,629,160 3.1% 2,629,160 3.7% 55–59 2,162,960 2.6% 2,162,960 3.0% 60–64 1,604,910 1.9% 1,604,910 2.2% 65–69 1,372,060 1.6% 1,372,060 1.9% 70–74 984,594 1.2% 984,594 1.4% 75–79 577,216 0.7% 577,216 0.8% 80+ 512,065 0.6% 512,065 0.7% Total 83,598,096 100.0% 71,373,504 100.0% Source: Author’s projection based on Spectrum. What Are the Health Benefits of Lower Fertility? So far, we have looked at the likely demographic profile of Egypt had the family planning program not succeeded. In this section, we look at the consequences for some important health variables related to child mortality and maternal mortality. Infant and Under-Five Mortality DHS defines high-risk births as those that fall into one of the following risk categories (the four “toos”): • Mother under age 18 (too young); • Mother over age 34 (too old); • Birth less than 24 months after previous birth (too close); and • Birth to a mother who has had more than three births (too many). DHS collects data on the risk factors facing women and on infant and child mortality. The data from five Egyptian DHS as presented in Figure 10 clearly demonstrate the relationship between births in the above risk categories and infant mortality rates. Each point shows how the percentage of births in a high-risk category is associated with a level of infant mortality. As the percentage of high-risk births falls, so do mortality rates. A similar picture holds for under-five mortality (U5MR). As depicted in Figure 11, another relationship pertains to fertility rates and the percentage of births in a high-risk category. Higher fertility is often associated with long periods of childbearing; thus, more births occur in the “too young” and “too old categories.” Moreover, births spaced too closely together often occur in high-fertility societies, with high parity and high fertility essentially the same. 10 Figure 10. High-Risk Births and Infant Mortality 2 12 22 32 42 52 62 72 82 92 30%35%40%45%50%55%60%65%70% High-Risk Births IM R 1988 1992 1995 2000 2003 Source: Various Egypt DHS. Figure 11. Relationship between Fertility and High-Risk Births 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 30%35%40%45%50%55%60%65%70% High-Risk Births TF R 1988 1992 1995 2000 2003 Source: Various Egypt DHS. 11 Using data from Egypt’s several DHS, we followed Ross’s analysis2 and established the slope3 of the relationship between the changes in IMR and U5MR and the changes in sk women. We also estimated slopes for changes in TFR and changes in the percen able 6). Table 6. Slopes of Child Mortality Relatio Change in infant mortality rate/Change in percen of at-risk births Change in under-five mortality rate/Change in percent of at-risk births Change in percent of at-risk births/Change in total fertility rate Source: Various DHS. We used these relationships to model the changes in contraceptive fertility) on infant and under-five mortality associated with changes in the pathway for the model follows: CPR Æ TFR Æ Percent of Women at Risk Æ IM CPR ÆTFR ÆPercent of Women at Risk Æ U5 We are therefore able to use these relationships to estimate how a highe affected infant and under-five mortality rates under the counterfactual sc Figure 12 shows that, if fertility followed the counterfactual scenario, th declined only slightly from 121 in 1980 to 95.8 in 2004 instead of to 33 fertility. Figure 12. Infant Mortality Rate 0.0 20.0 40.0 60.0 80.0 100.0 120.0 140.0 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 Actual Counterfactual 2 Email communication from John Ross, July 16, 2005. 3 The slope is the change in IMR or U5MR due to a change in the percent of at- the percentage of at-ri tage of at-risk women (T nships t 1.81 2.90 16.40 use’s effects (through changes in the counterfactual scenario. Thus, R MR r level of fertility would have enario. e infant mortality rate would have as it actually did with lower 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 95.8 33 Source: Author’s calculations. risk births. 12 Similarly, Figure 13 shows that, if the counterfactual fertility pattern had materialized, the under-five mortality rate would have fallen much more slowly according to our model. Under-F 0.0 50.0 100.0 150.0 200.0 250.0 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 9 Source: The pattern for under-five mortality rate is sim fallen to only 157.8 per 1,000 if fertility had re actual rate of 41 per 1,000 as recently observ almost four times higher under the counterfactu We used the different mortality rates combin scenario to estimate the annual number of infan Table 7. Estimated Ann 1980 Infant Deaths Counterfactual 192,768 209 Actual 187,228 158 Deaths averted 5,540 50 Deaths prevented 29 Under-Five Deaths Counterfactual 315,796 343 Actual 269,993 212 Deaths averted 45,802 130 Deaths prevented 35,054 95 4 We note that the underlying statistical model also p actual rate was 174 per 1,000 while the model predic 13 Figure 13. ive Mortality Rate 0 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual 157.8 41 Author’s calculations. ilar to that for the infant mortality rate and would have mained high under the counterfactual scenario versus the ed. Thus, the under-five mortality rate would have been al as under the actual scenario.4 ed with the different sizes of the population under each t and under-five deaths. Table 7 presents the estimates. ual Infant and Under-Five Deaths 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 ,649 225,037 233,252 249,888 274,003 ,786 102,806 85,265 71,231 59,902 ,863 122,231 147,987 178,657 214,100 ,135 80,657 83,500 107,826 113,997 ,801 369,355 383,301 411,125 451,383 ,806 140,944 107,382 86,665 74,424 ,995 228,411 275,919 324,460 376,959 ,364 160,176 169,948 207,926 212,051 Source: Author’s calculations. redicts a difference in the under-five mortality rates in 1980; the ts a rate of 197 per 1,000. The annual number of infant deaths would have been higher under the higher-fertility counterfactual scenario. Under the counterfactual, the number of infant deaths would have increased to 274,000 per year in 2005 as compared with falling to 60,000 per year in 2005 in the scenario that recreates the actual situation. If we add across the row for infant deaths averted over the period 1980 to 2005, we can calculate that a total 3.1 million infant deaths were averted as a result of the lower fertility resulting from the successful family planning program. The impact of fertility on infant deaths has two components. The first relates simply to the number of births—a higher fertility rate means a greater number of births and a greater number of babies at risk of death. The second component relates to the relationship discussed earlier with respect to fertility rates and the infant mortality rate. Hence, even if the number of births remained constant, we would expect a higher number of infant deaths in the case of higher fertility because the infant mortality rate would be higher. We considered such an effect by calculating the number of infant deaths that would have occurred in the case of the counterfactual population if the actual infant mortality rate were at work. Then, we subtracted the result from the counterfactual deaths. Table 7 shows difference in the row labeled “deaths prevented.” Figure 14 breaks down the annual infant deaths into the two components discussed above. Of the cumulative total of 3.1 million deaths averted between 1980 and 2005, 1.8 million can be attributed to the risk effect and 1.3 million to fewer births under the actual versus counterfactual scenario. Thus, it is interesting to see that more deaths were averted through the impact on the infant mortality rate than through the impact on the number of births. Clearly, family planning saves lives. Figure 14. Infant Deaths 0 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual Counterfactual births, lower IMR 1.3 Million due to lower births 1.8 Million due to lower risk Source: Author’s calculations. The differences in under-five mortality rate have an impact on the number of young children at risk of death. Table 7 shows the impact of the fertility scenarios on the annual number of under-five deaths. As noted, the statistical model predicts a higher under-five mortality rate in 1980 such that we already see differences in the annual number of under-five deaths (315,000 versus 279,000). By 2004, we estimate 14 that the combined effects of higher mortality rates and more young children mean that, under the counterfactual scenario, we expect 451,000 annual deaths among under-five children compared with our estimate of 74,000 in reality. Cumulatively, over the 25-year period, this amounts to over 6 million deaths averted among children under age five. Again, we also calculated under-five deaths prevented. We see, for example, that, of an estimated 376,000 under-five deaths in 2005, 212,000 were prevented as a consequence of the lower mortality rate that actually occurred relative to that which we predicted under the counterfactual scenario. Maternal Mortality We also estimated the impact of lower fertility on the number of mothers who would have lost their lives due to complications of pregnancy or childbirth. While we are not able to link the maternal mortality ratio statistically with fertility as we did for infant and under-five mortality, we can calculate the impact of lower fertility on maternal deaths through its impact on the number of births. Figure 15 shows that during the period 1980 to 2005 over 17,000 mothers’ lives were saved. Figure 15. Annual Maternal Deaths 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 6,000 7,000 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual 17,000 mothers' lives saved Source: Author’s calculations. What Are the Benefits in Terms of Lower Expenditures on Health and Social Programs? In this section, we look at the impacts of lower population growth on the costs of providing health, education, and food subsidies. The need to serve fewer people obviously results in cost savings. This retrospective study compares the amounts that we estimate were actually spent as compared with what might have been spent under the counterfactual scenario with its higher fertility rate. Previous USAID studies of the impact of Egypt’s lower fertility rate showed significant benefits of reduced fertility. Moreland’s 1996 study in the mid-1990s showed that LE 1invested in family planning would save over LE 30 in subsidies for education, food, health, housing, and water and sanitation. Chao 15 (2004) more recently found that benefits from family planning were even higher, with a benefit-cost ratio of more than 40, even though the study did not include housing. For several reasons, it is inappropriate to compare the benefit-cost ratios in the present analysis with those of the two earlier studies. First, the present study compares two scenarios in which fertility declines, although at different rates, whereas the previous studies held fertility constant in one scenario. Second, the time period for the present study is 25 years versus 30 for the other studies. Given that many benefits from changes in population growth are realized cumulatively over a long period, greater impacts are associated with a longer period. Third, the present study dates back to 1980, a period when social and health sector services were less prevalent; as a result, coverage rates were lower such that a smaller population would benefit from the services. Further, with Egypt a considerably poorer country 25 years ago, per capita spending in the social and health sectors was significantly lower. This means that estimated cost savings for a given change in population would be lower for the present study than for the other two. Even after consideration of methodological differences in the various studies, the present study points to significant savings resulting from Egypt’s family planning program, more than offsetting the program’s actual costs. Education As for education, we estimate what might have happened if the counterfactual scenario had unfolded. We first performed a retrospective projection of the number of students at each pre-university level of education in Egypt by using published figures on enrollment rates and appropriate age groups (6–10 for primary, 11–13 for preparatory, and 14–16 for secondary). Table 8. Projected Enrollment. Enrollment Type 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Primary Enrollment Counterfactual 4,024,555 5,066,370 6,766,920 8,667,708 9,457,101 10,963,498 Actual 4,024,555 5,009,119 6,348,949 7,480,754 7,289,101 7,948,889 Preparatory Enrollment Counterfactual 1,541,096 1,781,843 2,773,200 3,485,008 4,552,934 5,465,543 Actual 1,541,096 1,781,843 2,726,001 3,224,649 3,857,854 4,087,422 Secondary Enrollment Counterfactual 1,636,891 1,687,658 2,098,152 3,171,085 4,166,691 5,086,629 Actual 1,636,891 1,687,658 2,098,152 3,057,560 3,732,949 4,143,522 Total Enrollment Counterfactual 7,202,543 8,535,871 11,638,272 15,323,801 18,176,727 21,515,671 Actual 7,202,543 8,478,620 11,173,102 13,762,963 14,879,903 16,179,832 Source: Author’s calculations. Table 8 shows that, by 2005 under the counterfactual scenario, annual enrollment in all three cycles of pre-university enrollment would have topped 21 million versus just over 16 million as estimated for current enrollment. We used education expenditures per student to calculate education costs, noting that lower enrollment translates into cost savings. Due to lack of historical education cost data, we used the same unit costs as 16 Chao. Table 9 illustrates the counterfactual and actual scenarios. We estimate that by 2005 annual education costs would have reached LE 20,000 million if the counterfactual had held. However, with a lower number of children in school, costs were closer to LE 15,000 million. Cumulative savings over the 25-year period are estimated at LE 36,565 million. Table 9. Annual Education Costs for All Pre-University Cycles (millions of LE) 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Counterfactual 6,669 7,773 10,526 14,050 16,906 20,096 Actual 6,669 7,727 10,153 12,733 14,013 15,270 Source: Author’s calculations. Childhood Immunizations Next, we look at the cost of immunizing infants. Given that fertility affects the number of births, a higher fertility rate under the counterfactual scenario would have an immediate impact on the population under one year of age. In 1980, Egypt counted about 1.4 million children under one year old. By 2005, the number of infants was estimated to have grown to 1.7 million (see Figure 16). If, however, the counterfactual scenario had held, Egypt would have counted an additional 1 million infants, for a total of 2.7 million infants. Figure 16. Population under One Year Old 0 500,000 1,000,000 1,500,000 2,000,000 2,500,000 3,000,000 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual Source: Author’s calculations. 17 Figure 17. Child Immunization Costs 0.00 50.00 100.00 150.00 200.00 250.00 300.00 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 LE M ill io ns Counterfactual Actual 783 Million LE saved Source: Author’s calculations. The additional 1 million infants would have required early childhood vaccinations. With no immunization cost data available for Egypt, we estimated child immunization costs by using international costs for a fully immunized child. On the basis of the differences in the number of infants in Figure 16, we estimated that by 2005 annual early child immunization costs would total LE 283 million under the counterfactual scenario versus LE 179 million under the actual scenario, representing a cumulative savings in child immunization costs of LE 783 million (see Figure 17). Food Subsidies Egypt has a long tradition of subsidizing basic food items, notably flour, bread, sugar, cooking oil, and a variety of other commodities (IFPRC, 2001). While Egypt’s food subsidy program is designed to benefit the poor, a large segment of the population benefits mostly because subsidies for flour and bread reach virtually everyone. For this reason, we calculate food subsidy impacts for the total population rather than for a subpopulation. During the 1980s and 1990s, per capita subsidies remained fairly constant at between LE 40 and LE 60. Then, in 2003, subsidies increased to over LE 100 per capita and in 2004, to LE 164, as depicted in Figure 18. 18 Figure 18. Food Subsidy per Capita 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 LE /P er p er so n Source: Egypt Ministry of Supply and Domestic Trade. Figure 19 shows the impact of the per capita increase in the food subsidy. Total spending for the subsidy topped LE 11,847 million in 2004 and would have increased by LE 2,000 million under the counterfactual to LE 13,830 million. Over the 25-year comparison period, the savings in food subsidies is on the order of LE 8,489 million as a result of Egypt’s actual lower fertility as compared with the counterfactual projection. Figure 19. Food Subsidies 0.00 2,000.00 4,000.00 6,000.00 8,000.00 10,000.00 12,000.00 14,000.00 16,000.00 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05 Counterfactual Actual LE 8,489 Million Source: Author’s calculations. 19 How Do the Savings Compare We have seen significant cost savings in How do the savings compare with the cos Family Planning Expenditures As noted, USAID commissioned a ser combined with other data, allow us to est 2005. Table 4 showed the evolution of c donor funding for the period 1976 to 199 in family planning costs, we were able to We estimate that, from 1980 to 2005 government of Egypt spent LE 1,214 mi clients spent LE 210 million (Table 10). Table 10. Estimated Financing Source Government of Egypt Donor Sponsoring Agency and Client P Total Source: Family Comparing Family Planning with Sec If we total the cumulative savings over immunizations, food), we arrive at a fig figure that exceeds by far the LE 2,402 period (see Figure 20). Expenditu 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 30,000 35,000 40,000 45,000 50,000 LE (M ill io ns ) with the Costs of Family Planning? just three key sectors—education, immunizations, and food. ts of family planning over this period? ies of cost studies over the last 10 years. The studies, when imate the cost of the family planning program between 1980 and osts based on the studies. Zanaty and Robinson also reported on 8. With the Zanaty and Robinson data and estimates of the trend estimate family planning costs for the period 1980 to 1987. , of a total LE 2,402 million spent on family planning, the llion, donors spent LE 978 million, and sponsoring agencies and Family Planning Financing (millions LE) 1980–1988 1988–2003 1980–2005 271 943 1,214 258 720 978 ay 51 159 210 580 1,676 2,402 Planning Cost Studies and author’s calculations. tor Savings the 25-year period for the three sectors of interest (education, ure of LE 45,838 million in total cost savings for the sectors, a million spent on the family planning program during the same Figure 20. res on FP vs Expenditures Saved, 1980-2005 2,402 45,838 Expenditure on FP Expenditure Saved Source: Author’s calculations. 20 Conclusion In summary, we conclude that Egypt’s family planning program has yielded many benefits for Egypt. These include: • A population that is smaller by 12 million, nearly the size of Cairo; • A more favorable age distribution, with 10 million fewer young people in the nonworking ages; • A lower infant mortality rate, resulting in over 3 million fewer infant deaths during the last 25 years; • A lower mortality rate for children under age five, resulting in over 6 million fewer early- childhood deaths during the last 25 years; • Fewer maternal deaths, with 17,000 mothers’ lives saved over the last 25 years; and • Lower education, immunization, and food subsidy costs that far exceed family planning program costs. These accomplishments are the result of a highly cost-effective family planning program. The LE 2,402 million spent on family planning during the 25-year period between 1980 and 2005 was more than offset by the LE 45,838 million cost savings in education, immunization, and food subsidies. These savings have allowed Egypt to maintain and improve the quality of public services in these sectors and ultimately the quality of life of Egyptians. Undoubtedly, as other studies have shown, other sectors, such as general healthcare, housing, job opportunities, and national economic growth, have also benefited from the family planning program. With an expected decline in donor funding for family planning in the near future, the results presented here show that substantial benefits have already accrued to Egypt. It is clear that Egypt would be prudent to maintain the program at current and even higher levels by allocating funds to replace those that are expected to be reduced by the phaseout of international donors. 21 References International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRC). 2001. The Egyptian Food Subsidy System: Structure, Performance and Options for Reform. Washington, DC: IFPRC. Chao, Dennis. April 2004. Family Planning in Egypt Is a Sound Financial Investment. Washington, DC: POLICY Project. Moreland, Scott, ed., 1996. Investing in Egypt’s Future. Cairo: RAPID Project. Robinson, Warren C., and Fatma H. El-Zanaty, 1995. The Impact of Policy and Program on Fertility in Egypt: The Egyptian Family Planning Success Story. Washington, DC: OPTIONS II Project Robinson, Warren C., and Fatma H. El-Zanaty, 2005. The Demographic Revolution in Modern Egypt. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books. National Population Council (NPC). 1981–2004. Annual Analytical Statistical Family Planning Services Report. Cairo. CAPMAS. 2004. Statistical Year Books (various years from 1952 to 2003). Cairo. Sayed, H. AA and Abdalla, H. AM. (2005). Report on the Trends of the Costs of the Family Planning Program in Egypt: FY 1988/89 to FY 2002/2003, POLICY II Project. 22
Looking for other reproductive health publications?
The Supplies Information Database (SID) is an online reference library with more than 2000 records on the status of reproductive health supplies. The library includes studies, assessments and other publications dating back to 1986, many of which are no longer available even in their country of origin. Explore the database here.